“Americans have reached a point where ignorance, especially of anything
related to public policy, is an actual virtue,” the scholar Tom Nichols
writes in his timely new book, “The Death of Expertise.” “To reject the
advice of experts is to assert autonomy, a way for Americans to insulate
their increasingly fragile egos from ever being told they’re wrong
about anything. It is a new Declaration of Independence: No longer do we
hold these truths to be self-evident, we hold all
truths to be self-evident, even the ones that aren’t true. All things
are knowable and every opinion on any subject is as good as any other.” --"The Death of Expertise Explores How Ignorance Became a Virtue", book review by Michiko Kaukutani in the NY Times.
Scientific knowledge is a body of statements of varying degrees of certainty—some most unsure, some nearly sure, but none absolutely certain.” --Richard Feynman, 1988
A couple things made me want to write a short essay on science v politics in light of the upcoming March for Science. One topic came up in the Legislature and one in the Santa Fe New Mexican. Here are the two issues. Both involved mixing science and politics in a way that was not honest to the science. For science to be representing itself as objective, it has to be safely insulated from politically driven outcomes. One has to be willing to gore one's own ox.
I worked quite a bit with Stephanie Garcia-Richard on HB-50 this term. As anyone who has followed the North Mesa Mutts blog knows, I was critical of the bill she pre-filed and worked to craft a bill that would not be so polarizing. By the time a less onerous bill was introduced, it was too late to make any difference. But the science issue was the skewing of discussion by making invalid comparisons. Everytown for Gun Safety and to some degree our representative claimed that states with universal background check laws have a roughly 50% lower rate of domestic violence homicides and shootings of police. But even the sympathetic Politifact only gave that a rating of "half-true" and glossed over critical issues.
Politifact considered "background checks" in 14 states, California, Connecticut, Hawaii, Illinois, Iowa, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Nebraska, New Jersey, New York, North Carolina, Rhode Island and Pennsylvania. But this comparison is false on its face. These fourteen states differ in sociology, gun ownership rates, and in having quite different sets of gun laws (for a review of state gun laws, go here). All but two have extremely restrictive gun laws. For example, permits to purchase and heavy restrictions on handgun ownership are present in California, Connecticut, Hawaii, New Jersey, and New York, most of which have "may issue" handgun permitting laws (i.e., a law enforcement official can deny a permit application not on the basis of an applicant's qualifications but on a poorly defined law enforcement opinion of your suitability). A Firearms Owner Identification Card is required in Illinois. Etc. Finally, the before/after study of gun laws v gun crime in Connecticut involved the imposition of both a background check and permit to purchase system.
So the idea that gun violence in these states only differed because of having or not having universal background check laws is inaccurate and the resulting assumption that background checks are the only state to state differences falsely insinuates that any differences in homicide rates are due to background checks. Even a partial reading of the literature (which is all I had time for this year) suggests that a background check law like suggested by HB50 may have a small but measurable effect on gun violence by putting one more roadblock between prohibited persons and guns. It would be a roadblock, not a wall.
The ‘March for Science’ is a good reminder not to take for granted the
interactions between science, society and public policy, and that
ignoring them or not investing in them can have significant
consequences. But it also emphatically reminds the science community
that it too must respect and engage with the ever-evolving contract
between science and society. Marching may be seen as one way of
engaging, but it cannot replace the harder work of making ourselves
available, making our work relevant and making science difficult to
ignore – not just on April 22.
Prof. Sir Peter Gluckman, Prime Minister's Chief Science Advisor, New Zealand,
Another bit of political science was played by former Los Alamos resident Tony Heller in a recent New Mexican article. But his article is weak. After disputing the value of using polls of scientists to decide topics regarding climate change, Tony tells us that "...There are tens of thousands of scientists who agree with (EPA Secretary Scott) Pruitt’s questions about human impact...". So really. Do we decide these things on poll v poll? Do we even know the credentials of who was polled?
The real issue where we can likely get consensus in the geophysical and geochemical community is that massively increasing CO2 in the atmosphere over pre-industrial (but post-Pleistocene) levels will affect climate sufficiently to impact human activities. The question is how much, and at what cost to adapt or mitigate. On that topic, in a recent paper discussing the uncertainty of climate calculations and the resulting effects on mitigation, Yoichi Kava, Mitsutsune Yamaguchi, and Keigo Akimoto review the present state of uncertainty on climate sensitivity to CO2 and note that in going from AR4 to AR5 (i.e., the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change's 4th and 5th assessments of climate change) the consensus value for equilibrium (not transient) climate sensitivity ("ECS") to CO2 went from an estimated range of 2.0-4.5 deg C per atmospheric CO2 doubling to 1.5-4.5 deg C. Lewis and Curry put the range considerably lower (see discussion in their link). But its the uncertainty that kills planning. The authors show a graph of their estimated abatement costs to keep the equilibrium temperature from rising more than 2 deg C (i.e., the Paris accords) for a climate sensitivity value of 3 deg v 2.5 deg per doubling. The cost estimates for the two sensitivities differ by roughly an order of magnitude when run out to the half-century. There are undoubtedly other calculations out there as well; I'm not trying to cherry-pick. This is a blog, not a research paper.
Figure 2 from Kava et al. |
Imagine wanting to buy a house and not knowing if the total costs of home ownership were $250,000 or 2.5 million dollars. Now, imagine yourself a politician trying to decide on a path forward on climate policy using those same economic uncertainties. Small wonder that folks want to believe the version of science that fits their own interests.
The problem is, underestimating climate sensitivity could be a disaster. If climate sensitivity is on the low side, then even if we overshoot emissions the results could be quite manageable in terms of sea level rise and other modelled changes. As Judith Curry has said on her blog, if reality conforms to the high sensitivity tail of the various climate model's uncertainties (and note these are all forward projecting models) the resulting costs would likely be very high. For a recent, real world example of underestimating Ma Nature, one has to only look at the Fukushima disaster. TEPCO built a 20 foot seawall because it underestimated the highest likely tsunami. Ma Nature handed the company a 45 foot tsunami. The rest is history. Imagine a disaster like that on a global scale. So it is prudent for the industrialized and industrializing nations to be light on the carbon emissions throttle as we think are way through this research. We can't run climate in reverse.
"The truth knocks on the door and you say, ‘Go away, I’m looking for the truth,’ and so it goes away. Puzzling." -- Robert M. Pirsig
"It is clear...that
the impact of a mere 0.5 °C difference in climate sensitivity is of
critical significance for policy objectives, which is especially
significant given the large uncertainties over climate sensitivity. It
is scientific community’s vital role to narrow the uncertainty range of
ECS. At the same time it is critically important for policymakers in
Paris to know that they are in a position to make decisions under large
uncertainty of ECS."
3 comments:
Hmm, let's assume mid-level sensitivity to carbon emissions and that the US contributes a quarter of the global carbon emission total. Under an "America First" approach, how much is it worth to places like Holland and various low-lying island nations to pay us to reduce our CO2 so they don't simply disappear? After all, mostly, we've mostly only got Florida to lose. Perhaps, Mexico, not wanting to get even hotter, would pay for that darned wall if we shot less CO2 into the air in exchange. Sign me, "the advocate for the devil." Seriously, we DO live in strange times...
But who will pay India and China to reduce their carbon footprint? I suppose one could put a tax on all products made using high emission scenerios and use that money to build a wall around Holland?
The US can become 100% renewable tomorrow, but as Khal points out China, Inida, Russia and friends are all large producers. Every whisp of gas, lump of coal, and drop of oil will burn until it is not economical to do so. We can't jeapordize the well being of tens and likely hundreds of millions of people worldwide today for potential effects centuries from now. Pushing solar, wind, fusion and the like beyond economic parity with fossil fuels is the only way to push back on man's contribution to climate change.
Post a Comment